The need for wellbeing measurement in context

Date
Author(s)
Macroeconomic Group - Domestic
Presenter
Dr David Gruen|Duncan Spender
Position
Executive Director
Location
Canberra
Topic

Downloads

On previous occasions I have discussed the Treasury’s wellbeing framework (summarised in the attachment) and issues with the measurement of wellbeing.2 To shed more light on both the role of the Treasury wellbeing framework and our perspective on wellbeing measurement, today I will focus on the broader context in which the Treasury’s wellbeing framework sits.

Treasury can help improve wellbeing without having in its possession a complete, agreed approach to wellbeing measurement.

  • The Treasury mission requires us to serve our Ministers, and the nature of democracy suggests a positive relationship between the service of Ministers and improving societal wellbeing.
  • The Treasury wellbeing framework reminds Treasury staff to inform their advice with an understanding that wellbeing is driven by several distinct considerations and that trade-offs will often be required. This assists Ministers to make value judgments, taking into account community preferences and hence supporting wellbeing.
  • The Treasury wellbeing framework requires us to undertake objective and thorough analysis using the best available tools. Rigorous application of well-worn economic tools provides us with some assurance that the policy recommendations that result are consistent with improving wellbeing.
  • And, provided that market and government failures are addressed, we can have some confidence that people and businesses going about their lives will tend to improve wellbeing.

Moreover, Treasury’s broad wellbeing objective is accompanied by more specific — and more measurable — objectives.

So while efforts to improve and get agreement on wellbeing measures are well worthwhile, public policy agencies like the Treasury can nonetheless carry out their responsibilities in the absence of a complete, agreed approach to wellbeing measurement.

Measuring Wellbeing

Before discussing how the Treasury carries out its responsibilities without there being an agreed approach to wellbeing measurement, I want to briefly recap some general thoughts on such measurement.

Wellbeing measurement is important. In the words of the Sen-Stiglitz-Fitoussi Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, “what we measure affects what we do”.3 What we measure affects judgments about the current state of affairs and what policy responses are needed. Policy choices need to be based on both reason and empirical evidence; theory and practice need to work together.

The Treasury wellbeing framework requires staff to use the best available evidence and measures. The Treasury is an intensive and extensive user of measures that, when brought together, give an indication of the wellbeing of the Australian people. Such measures also help to evaluate our performance.

But for the foreseeable future we will continue to face an array of differing approaches to wellbeing measurement, rather than having in our possession a fully agreed approach.

This is the case because a fully agreed approach to wellbeing measurement would require full agreement on the concept of wellbeing itself.

  • While there is much agreement as to things that are important to wellbeing, there is no common all-encompassing conceptualisation of wellbeing. Even an individual’s conception of his or her own wellbeing can be conflicted, and this conception needs to be examined and aggregated across individuals before we can arrive at an agreed concept of the wellbeing of society.
  • The Treasury’s wellbeing framework starts with a broad-ranging statement that wellbeing primarily reflects a person’s substantive freedom to lead a life they have reason to value. This language reflects a pluralistic approach to understanding wellbeing, drawn from the capabilities approach of Amartya Sen. The language doesn’t prescribe what it is that is valued, and it doesn’t say how to aggregate across individuals.

Alongside difficulties arising from conceptual differences, there are also various practical difficulties with wellbeing measurement.

  • The measurement of material wellbeing involves significant difficulties with measuring quality and non-market services.
  • The measurement of opportunities and capabilities involves attempting to measure what people could do, as opposed to what they actually do.4
  • The measurement of self-reported subjective wellbeing is complicated by the various types of wellbeing that could be reported (e.g. mood happiness, life satisfaction or feelings of agency and autonomy).
  • And the estimation of future wellbeing involves taking a position on (at least) future preferences, discoveries, technological developments, events and population growth.

Serving Ministers

But the lack of a fully agreed approach to wellbeing measurement does not pose an insurmountable problem for Treasury’s use of its wellbeing framework, for various reasons.

First, Treasury’s main role is to serve the people of Australia through the Government of the day. That is, through its role in supporting Ministers discharge their responsibilities. Given the positive relationship between democracy and improving societal wellbeing, public servants in a democratic society should have confidence that serving their Ministers, by providing advice and helping to implement policies, tends to improve wellbeing. This is true even if the measurement of wellbeing remains far from perfect.

Given the Treasury’s traditional focus on economics, it is worth mentioning that this view of the positive relationship between democracy and wellbeing has strong foundations in economic theory, and is a view shared by economists who otherwise vary considerably in their world view.5

For instance, modern public finance theory was born more than a century ago when economists such as the Swedish economist Knut Wicksell directed the recently developed tools of marginal theory towards an examination of government behaviour. Rather than simply assuming that government serves the public interest, Wicksell undertook an assessment of the circumstances in which government provision of public goods would be just and efficient, based on an aggregation of the interests of individuals. Importantly, his analysis explored various voting rules and highlighted the importance of universal franchise.6

Subsequent economists like Duncan Black and Anthony Downs explored how competition can lead rational self-interested politicians to act in the interests of the majority, while Schumpeter explored how political leadership, beyond mere representation of the median voter, can be welfare-enhancing when underpinned by periodic voting.7 Theorists like William Niskanen and James Buchanan have explored the particular interests of public servants and politicians and the structures in which they operate, and the importance of voters being well-informed.8 And seminal work on voting rules and group dynamics has been added by the likes of Kenneth Arrow and Mancur Olson.9

While these economists explored the various flaws in democratic models, they also helped build a strong economic argument linking the service of elected politicians with improvements in wellbeing.

So while public servants can sometimes be cynical about the political process, they should gain confidence from the general positive relationship between service in a democracy and wellbeing, notwithstanding difficulties in measuring that wellbeing.

Distinguishing elements of wellbeing assis
ts ministerial decision-making

But public servants do more than just respond to Ministers. They use frameworks to advise Ministers.

The Treasury’s wellbeing framework reminds Treasury staff to explore, and advise Ministers of, the distinct impacts of policies on various considerations, such as the level and distribution of material consumption, health, and environmental amenity.

The Treasury wellbeing framework identifies five dimensions that directly or indirectly have important implications for wellbeing and are particularly relevant to Treasury. These dimensions are:

  • the set of opportunities available to people, including — but not limited to — the level of goods and services that can be consumed;
  • the distribution of those opportunities across the Australian people;
  • the sustainability of those opportunities over time;
  • the overall level and allocation of risk borne by individuals and the community; and
  • the complexity of the choices facing individuals and the community.

In response to a particular public policy issue, the Treasury may identify options that maximise the level of certain opportunities or minimise the overall level of risk or complexity. The Treasury may also be able to outline how a policy affects the distribution of opportunities, risk and complexity across the population and over time (noting that the selection of a distributional measure involves normative judgments about what is being distributed, among whom, and whether the measure uses equality or adequacy as a reference point).

In doing this the Treasury cannot come to definitive conclusions that a certain distribution is appropriate, that a certain weight should be given to level versus distributional considerations, or that some types of opportunities are more important than others. These are ultimately decisions to be made by elected politicians, who are called to make value judgments, taking into account community preferences and hence supporting wellbeing.

But, the wellbeing framework helps Treasury staff assist Ministers to make these value judgments.

For instance, the framework’s reference to the level of goods and services for consumption is accompanied by references to various distributional concerns. This reminds staff to consider and outline impacts on both efficiency and distribution — both when the explicit purpose of a policy is to redistribute, and when it is not.

Distributional analysis may reveal that a suite of policies both assists and hinders the same group of people; such a result presumably does not serve distributional goals, whatever those goals may be.10 It may reveal that the winners from a certain policy could compensate the losers. It may highlight community views on fairness and other reasons for considering distribution, or it may highlight differences in the distribution for one concept (such as income) but not for another (such as consumption).

So it is not the purpose of the wellbeing framework to allow staff to simply point to options that maximise wellbeing; this is impossible given the absence of an agreed approach to measuring wellbeing. Rather, the wellbeing framework helps staff set out some dimensions of wellbeing to hopefully help Ministers make well-informed value judgments consistent with improving wellbeing.

Treasury draws on powerful, well-established tools to provide thorough analysis

The Treasury’s wellbeing framework also requires us to undertake objective and thorough analysis using the best available analytical frameworks.

The Treasury faces myriad claims of market failure and needs to draw on economic frameworks to distinguish the well-based claims from the rest. Various economic frameworks are discussed in documents like the Best Practice Regulation Handbook, produced by the Office of Best Practice Regulation in consultation with agencies including the Treasury. The Handbook outlines various types of market failure, including monopoly and abuse of market power, asymmetric information, externalities, and non-rivalrous or non-excludable goods. It also outlines instances where government may or may not be able to improve the situation.11

The Treasury can draw on recent economic research on systematic failures in personal decision-making, which applies to the public, but also to public officials.12 And the Treasury can also draw on literature on types of government failures, including work on fiscal illusion, the theory of second best, and barriers to policy reversal.13

Treasury’s wellbeing framework also requires staff to gather the best available empirical evidence, in recognition that theory is always more reliable when partnered with empirics.

This partnership of robust theory and available empirics can provide considerable assurance that the resulting policy recommendations are consistent with improving wellbeing, notwithstanding the absence of comprehensive wellbeing measures.

The relationship between improving personal wellbeing and societal wellbeing

A degree of assurance also comes from the nature of individuals in a market-based economy.

The Treasury’s approach to wellbeing is cast from the perspective of individuals. As I have said already, the Treasury considers that wellbeing primarily reflects a person’s substantive freedom to lead a life they have reason to value.

This is an economic approach and is predicated on the idea that, provided that market and government failures are addressed and the government provides a conducive environment, we should have some confidence that individuals going about their lives will tend to improve their personal wellbeing, the wellbeing of those they care for, and, in part through market transactions, societal wellbeing. (In providing a conducive environment, in general government actions will have implications for the distribution of society’s resources across individuals, and for improving equality of opportunity.)

This approach is consistent with Australia’s democratic and market-based society, and puts the importance of wellbeing measures in context. While better wellbeing measurement will be valuable, we nonetheless have less need for such aggregate measures than do states that specialise in central planning.

Treasury has both broad and specific goals

When considering the Treasury’s need for wellbeing measurement, it is also important to note that the Treasury has been tasked with specific, more measurable, goals alongside its broad wellbeing goal.

These specific goals include the achievement of strong, sustainable economic growth, the efficient provision of Commonwealth payments to the State and Territory governments, the preparation of documents in compliance with the Charter of Budget Honesty, effective taxation and retirement income arrangements, competitive and efficient markets, a reduced regulatory burden on business, and improved housing supply and affordability.14

Each of these goals is important, and success against each of them can be measured more readily that success against the broad wellbeing goal.

A measure approach to new measures

So while efforts to improve the measurement of wellbeing are important, public policy agencies like the Treasury can nonetheless carry out their responsibilities in the absence of a fully agreed, and comprehensive, approach to wellbeing measurement.

Given this, we should take a dispassionate approach when looking at efforts to improve the measurement of wellbeing. We can weigh the potential benefits of efforts to improve wellbeing measures against the costs of those efforts and the risks that resulting measures will be flawed, be misu
sed or go unused.

Conclusion

Australia is at the forefront of wellbeing measurement. The Measures of Australia’s Progress project of the Australian Bureau of Statistics was ahead of its time, and continues to provide an insightful, wide-ranging and balanced dashboard of important indicators to assist public debate and understanding. This dashboard approach is the best way to grapple with perhaps the most important and challenging measurement question there can be.

It is important that we continue to counter misuse of existing measures, strive to improve individual measures, and promote consideration of a broad array of measures. There is much to gain from such efforts.

That said, it is important to note that, in the absence of precise wellbeing measurements, public service and government decision-making are not blind. They continue to be guided by the democratic process, economic theory, and conscientious analysis. This is the context for the Treasury’s wellbeing framework, and it leaves the Treasury as an eager, rather than dependent, user of wellbeing measures.

Attachment: The Treasury wellbeing framework

In undertaking its mission Treasury takes a broad view of wellbeing as primarily reflecting a person’s substantive freedom to lead a life they have reason to value.

This view encompasses more than is directly captured by commonly used measures of economic activity. It gives prominence to respecting the informed preferences of individuals, while allowing scope for broader social actions and choices. It is open to both subjective and objective notions of wellbeing, and to concerns for outcomes and consequences as well as for rights and liberties.

Treasury brings a whole-of-economy approach to providing advice to government based on an objective and thorough analysis of options. To facilitate that analysis, we have identified five dimensions that directly or indirectly have important implications for wellbeing and are particularly relevant to Treasury. These dimensions are:

  • The set of opportunities available to people. This includes not only the level of goods and services that can be consumed, but good health and environmental amenity, leisure and intangibles such as personal and social activities, community participation and political rights and freedoms.
  • The distribution of those opportunities across the Australian people. In particular, that all Australians have the opportunity to lead a fulfilling life and participate meaningfully in society.
  • The sustainability of those opportunities available over time. In particular, consideration of whether the productive base needed to generate opportunities (the total stock of capital, including human, physical, social and natural assets) is maintained or enhanced for current and future generations.
  • The overall level and allocation of risk borne by individuals and the community. This includes a concern for the ability, and inability, of individuals to manage the level and nature of the risks they face.
  • The complexity of the choices facing individuals and the community. Our concerns include the costs of dealing with unwanted complexity, the transparency of government and the ability of individuals and the community to make choices and trade-offs that better match their preferences.

These dimensions reinforce our conviction that trade-offs matter deeply, both between and within dimensions. The dimensions do not provide a simple checklist: rather their consideration provides the broad context for the use of the best available economic and other analytical frameworks, evidence and measures.

References

Arrow, Kenneth 1963 Social Choice and Individual Values, Second edition, John Wiley and Sons, New York.

Australian Government 1998 A Guide to Regulation, Second edition, Office of Regulation Review, Canberra.

Australian Government 2007 Best Practice Regulation Handbook, Office of Best Practice Regulation, Canberra.

Black, Duncan 1948 ‘On the Rationale of Group Decision-making’, Journal of Political Economy, 56(1), pp. 23-34.

Buchanan, James 1975 The Limits of Liberty, University of Chicago, Chicago

Downs, Anthony 1957 An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper, New York

Fleurbaey, Marc 2009 ‘Beyond GDP: The Quest for a Measure of Social Welfare’, Journal of Economic Literature, 47(4), pp. 1029 1075.

Glaeser, Edward 2005 ‘Paternalism and Psychology’, Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper 2097, Harvard, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Gorecki, Stephanie, David Gruen and Shane Johnson 2011 ‘Measuring Wellbeing in Theory and Practice’, Treasury Working Paper No. 2011-02, Canberra.

Gruen, David and Joanne Wilkie 2009 ‘New Paradigms to Measure Progress’, Economic Roundup, Issue 4, pp. 1‐9.

Hall, Peter 1993 ‘Policy Paradigms, Social Learning and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain’, Comparative Politics, 25(3), pp. 275-296.

Inglehart, Ronald, Robert Foa, Christopher Peterson and Christian Welzel 2008 ‘Development, Freedom, and Rising Happiness: A Global Perspective (1981-2007)’, Perspectives on Psychological Science 3(4), pp. 264-285.

Inglehart, Richard and Hans-Dieter Klingemann 2000 ‘Genes, culture, democracy and happiness’, in Ed Diener and Eunkook (eds) Subjective Well-being Across Cultures, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Kelly, James and Stephanie Gorecki 2012 ‘Treasury’s Wellbeing Framework’ Economic Roundup, Issue 3, pp.27-64.

Lindahl, Erik 1919, ‘Just Taxation — A Positive Solution’ (Elizabeth Henderson trans), in Richard Musgrave and Alan Peacock (eds) 1967 Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, MacMillan, London.

Lipsey, Richard and Kelvin Lancaster 1956-57 ‘The General Theory of Second Best’, The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), pp. 11-32.

Niskanen, William 1971 Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago, Aldine.

Niskanen, William 2006 ‘Limiting Government: The Failure of “Starve the Beast”’, Cato Journal, 26(3).

Olson, Mancur 1965 The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Podger, Andrew 2011 ‘Ian Castles and the Henry Tax/Transfers Review’, Keynote Address — HC Coombs Policy Forum, Australian National University, Canberra.

Schumpeter, Joseph 1942, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Fifth edition, George Allen and Unwin, London.

Stiglitz, Joseph, Amartya Sen and Jean-Paul Fitoussi 2009 ‘Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress’, Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress.

Tasic, Slavisa 2009 ‘The Illusion of Regulatory Competence’, Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 21(4) pp. 423-436.

Treasury 1964 ‘The Meaning and Measurement of Economic Growth’, Supplement to the Treasury Economic Bulletin, November, Canberra.

Treasury 1973 ‘Economic Growth: Is It Worth Having?’ Treasury Economic Paper No. 2, Canberra.

Treasury 2004 ‘Policy advice and Treasury’s wellbeing framework’, Economic Roundup, Winter, Canberra.

Treasury 2011 Treasury Strategic Framework, Canberra.


1 Address by the first author to the Economic Growth and Wellbeing Symposium in honour of Ian Castles AO, held by the Academy of the Social Sciences in Australia and the Crawford School at the Australian National Universi
ty, 22 November 2012. We thank Harry Greenwell, James Kelly, Martin Parkinson and Angela Woo for helpful comments.

2 See Gorecki, Stephanie, David Gruen and Shane Johnson 2011 ‘Measuring wellbeing in theory and practice’, Treasury Working Paper No. 2011-02, Canberra, and Gruen, David and Joanne Wilkie 2009 ‘New paradigms to measure progress’, Economic Roundup, Issue 4, pp. 1‐9. For a recent detailed discussion of the Treasury wellbeing framework, its history and its elements, see Kelly, James and Stephanie Gorecki 2012 ‘Treasury’s Wellbeing Framework’ Economic Roundup, Issue 3, pp.27-64.

3 Stiglitz, Joseph, Amartya Sen and Jean-Paul Fitoussi 2009 ‘Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress’, Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, p. 7.

4 Measurement is a notorious problem for Sen’s capabilities approach to wellbeing (Fleurbaey, Marc 2009, ‘Beyond GDP: The Quest for a Measure of Social Welfare’, Journal of Economic Literature, 47(4), pp.  1029-1075).

5 There is also empirical evidence of a positive relationship between democracy and subjective wellbeing measures, after controlling for economic development and initial subjective wellbeing levels (Inglehart, Ronald, Robert Foa, Christopher Peterson and Christian Welzel 2008 ‘Development, Freedom, and Rising Happiness: A Global Perspective (1981-2007)’ Perspectives on Psychological Science 3(4), pp. 264-285.
Given the economic foundations for democracy, it is perhaps no coincidence that Ian Castles served as Electoral Commissioner.

6 Wicksell’s support for universal franchise was intimately combined with support for requirements for unanimity or near unanimity in government decision-making. (See Wicksell, Knut, 1896 ‘A New Principle of Just Taxation’ (James Buchanan trans) in Richard Musgrave and Alan Peacock (eds), 1967, Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, MacMillan, London.)

7 Black, Duncan 1948 ‘On the Rationale of Group Decision-making’, Journal of Political Economy, 56(1), pp. 23-34; Downs, Anthony 1957 An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper, New York; Schumpeter, Joseph 1942 Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Fifth edition, George Allen and Unwin, London.

8 Niskanen, William 1971 Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago, Aldine; Niskanen, William 2006 ‘Limiting Government: the Failure of “Starve the Beast”’ Cato Journal, 26(3); Buchanan, James 1975 The Limits of Liberty, University of Chicago, Chicago.
While not in the field of public finance, the economist and sociologist Max Weber provided seminal contributions on the nature of bureaucracy (see Musgrave, Richard and Peggy Musgrave 1989 Public Finance in Theory and Practice, Fifth edition, McGraw Hill, Singapore, p.103). And in the same era as Knut Wicksell, Amilcare Puviani introduced the concept of fiscal illusion (in which there is a disconnect between awareness of government spending and awareness of (eventual) taxation) (see Lindahl, Erik 1919, ‘Just Taxation — A Positive Solution’ (Elizabeth Henderson trans) in Richard Musgrave and Alan Peacock (eds), 1967, Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, MacMillan, London, p175). The importance of voters being well informed in turn highlights the importance of freedom of political participation, speech and association and a free press.

9 Arrow, Kenneth 1963 Social Choice and Individual Values, Second edition, John Wiley and Sons, New York; Olson, Mancur 1965 The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

10 The combined analysis of the tax and transfer system championed by Ian Castles is an example of an approach that allows the coherence of nominally separate systems to be tested (Podger, Andrew 2011 ‘Ian Castles and the Henry Tax/Transfers Review’, Keynote Address — HC Coombs Policy Forum, Australian National University, Canberra).

11 Australian Government 2007 Best Practice Regulation Handbook, Office of Best Practice Regulation, Canberra.

12 Tasic, Slavisa 2009 ‘The Illusion of Regulatory Competence’, Critical Review: a Journal of Politics and Society 21(4) pp. 423-436; Glaeser, Edward 2005 ‘Paternalism and Psychology’ Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper 2097, Harvard, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

13 Lipsey, Richard and Kelvin Lancaster 1956-57 ‘The General Theory of Second Best’, The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), pp. 11-32; Hall, Peter 1993 ‘Policy Paradigms, Social Learning and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain, Comparative Politics, 25(3), pp. 275-296.

14 The idea that public policy should be concerned with both economic growth and broader concepts such as wellbeing is a longstanding one for both the economics profession and the Treasury. The conceptual distinction between welfare/utility and income/output was recognised by the pioneers of the discipline, including Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill. It was further explored by later economists such as Kelvin Lancaster and Gary Becker (see, for example, the discussion of the conceptual basis for the Treasury’s Wellbeing Framework in Treasury 2004 ‘Policy advice and Treasury’s wellbeing framework’, Economic Roundup, Winter, Canberra, pp.2-5). Given this history, it should be no surprise that the Treasury has for a long time incorporated both economic growth and wellbeing considerations into its analysis and advice. For example, a 1964 Treasury paper outlined the importance of measured economic activity but noted that a change in the market value of output is nonetheless not a comprehensive or unambiguous measure of the change in total welfare (Treasury 1964 ‘The Meaning and Measurement of Economic Growth’, Supplement to the Treasury Economic Bulletin, November, Canberra). Many of the same points were made in the Treasury 1973 paper, ‘Economic Growth: Is It Worth Having?’ (Treasury Economic Paper No. 2, Canberra), to which Ian Castles made major contributions. A more limited approach essentially focused on growth in GDP, or in GDP per capita, would represent a partial approach unsuited to the analysis of many of the most important public policy issues.